Winning Isn’t Everything: Corruption in Sumo Wrestling
By MARK DUGGAN AND STEVEN D. LEVITT*
There is a growing appreciation among econ-
omists of the need to better understand the role
that corruption plays in real-world economies.
Although some have argued that it can be w el-
fare enhancing (Nathaniel Leff, 1964), most
commentators believe that a willingness to ac-
cept bribes (or similar forms of corruption) in
either the public or the private sector reduc es
economic ef ciency (Andrei Shleifer and
Robert W. Vishny, 1 993). As a result, g overn-
ments and rms often create incentives to mo-
tivate their employees to be honest (Gary S.
Becker and George J. Stigler, 1974).
While it is generally agreed that corruption is
widespread, th ere is little rigorous empirical
research on the subject. Because of corruption’s
illicit nature, those who engage in corruption
attempt not to leave a trail. As a consequence,
much of the existing evidence on corruption is
anecdotal in nature. More systematic empirical
substantiation of corrupt practices is unlikely to
appear in typical data sources. Rather, research-
ers must adopt nonstandard approaches in an
attempt to ferret out indirect evidence of
corruption.
To date, there have been only a handful of
studies that attempt to systematically document
the impact of corruption on economic o ut-
comes. The rst empirical study of corruption
dates to 1846 when Quetelet documented th at
the height distribution among French males
based on measurements taken at conscription
was normally distributed ex cept for a puzzling
shortage of men measuring 1.571.597 meters
(roughly 5 feet 2 inches to 5 feet 3 inches) and
an excess number of men below 1.57 meters.
Not coincidentally, the minimum height for
conscription into the Imperial army was 1.57
meters (Stephen Stigler, 1986). More recent em-
pirical work on corruption includes R obert H.
Porter and J. Douglas Zona (1993), which nds
evidence that construction companies collude
when bidding for state highway contracts by
meeting before the auction, designating a seri-
ous bidder, and having other cartel members
submit correspondingly higher bids. R. Preston
McAfee (1992) details a wid e variety of bid-
rigging schemes. Paulo Mauro (1995) uses sub-
jective indices of corruption across countries to
demonstrate a correlation between corrupt gov-
ernments and lower rates of economic growth,
although the relationship may not be causal.
Ray Fisman (2001) analyzes how stock prices
of Indonesian rms uctuate with changes in
former Prime Minister Suharto’s health status.
Firms with close connections to Suharto, which
presumably bene t from corruption within the
regime, decline substantially more than other
Indonesian rms when Suharto’s health weak-
ens. Whether the rents accruing to those close to
Suharto are due to corruption or simply bad
policy, however, is hard to determine. Rafael Di
Tella and Ernesto Schargrodsky (2000) docu-
ment that the prices paid for b asic inputs at
public hospitals in Buenos Aires fall by 10–20
percent after a corruption crackdown.
In this paper we look for corruption among
Japan’s elite sumo wrestlers. While acknowl-
edging th at sumo wrestling is not itself a subject
of direct interest to economists, we believe that
this case study nonetheless provides potentially
valuable insights. First, if corrupt practices
thrive here, one might suspect that no institution
is safe. Sumo wrestling is the national sport of
Japan, with a 2,000-year tradition and a focus
on honor, ritual, and history that may be unpar-
alleled in athletics.
1
Moreover, Japan is generally
* Duggan: Department of Economics, University of Chi-
cago, 1126 East 59th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, and National
Bureau of Economic Research (e-mail: mduggan@midway
.uchicago.edu); Levitt: American Bar Foundation and De-
partment of Economics, University of Chicago, 1126 East
59th Street, Chicago, IL 60637 (e-mail: slevitt@midway
.uchicago.edu). We would like to thank Gary Becker, Casey
Mulligan, Andrei Shleifer, Stephen Stigler, Mark West, two
anonymous referees, seminar participants, and especially
Serguey Braguinsky for helpful comments. Kyung-Hong
Park provided truly outstandin g research assistance. Levitt
gratefully acknowledges the research su pport of the Na-
tional Science Foundation and Slo an Foundation.
1
See Mark West (1997) for an examination of the legal
rules and informal norms that govern sumo wrestling in Japan.
1594
found to have relatively low rates of corruption
in cross-country comparisons (Transparency In-
ternational, 20 00).
2
Second, because of the sim-
plicity of the institutional framework, it is easy
to understand and model t he incentives facing
participants. Third, data to test for match rig-
ging are readily available. While the exact tech-
niques we utilize for studying corrupt behavior
in sumo wrestling will require modi cation be-
fore being applied to more substantive a pplica-
tions, our analysis may nonetheless aid future
researchers in that task.
The key institutional feature of sumo wres-
tling that makes it ripe for corruption is the
existence of a sharp nonlinearity in the payoff
function for competitors. A sumo tournament
(
basho
) involves 66 wrestlers (
rikishi
) partici-
pating in 15 bouts each. A wrestler who
achieves a winning record (eight wins or more,
known as
kachi-koshi
) is guaranteed to rise up
the of cial ranking (
banzuke
); a wrestler with a
losing record (
make-koshi
) falls in the rankings.
A wre stler’s rank is a source of prestige, the
basis for salary determination, and also in u-
ences the perks that he enjoys.
3
Figure 1 demonstrates empirically the impor-
tance of an eighth win t o a wrestler. The hori-
zontal axis of the gure is the number of wins a
wrestler achieves in a tournament; the vertical
axis is the average change in rank as a conse-
quence of the tournament. The change in rank is
a positive function of the number of wins. With
the exception of the eighth win, th e relationship
is nearly linear: each additional victory is worth
approximately three sp ots in the rankings. The
critical eighth win—which results in a substan-
tial promotion i n rank rather than a demotion—
garners a wrestler approximately 11 spots in the
ranking, or roughly four times the value of the
typical victory. Consequently, a wrestler enter-
ing the nal match of a tournament with a 7-7
record has far more to gain from a victory than
an opponent wit h a record of, say, 8-6 has to
lose. There will also b e incentives for forward-
looking wrestlers to rig matches o n earlier days
of the tournament.
4
According to our rough
calculations, moving up a single spot in the
rankings is worth on average approxima tely
$3,000 a year to a wrestler, so the potential
gains to trade may be substantial if the wrestlers
x a match.
5
Of course, no legally binding
contract can be written.
In this paper, we examine more than a decade
of data for Japan’s sumo e lite in search of
evidence demonstrating or refuting claims of
match rigging. We u ncover overwhelming evi-
dence that match rigging occurs in the nal days
of sumo tournaments. Wrestlers who are on the
margin for attaining their eighth victory win far
more often than would be expected. Hi gh win-
ning percentages by themselves, however, are
2
Nevertheless, in recent years, sumo wrestling has been
dogged by allegations of rigged matches, none of wh ich
have been substantiated. Of cials from the Japanese Sumo
Association dismiss these complaints as fabrications on the
part of disgraced former wrestlers. Ultimately, despite years
of allegations, no formal disciplinary actions have been
taken towar ds any wrestler.
3
For instance, the lowest-ranked wrestlers in the heya
must rise early each morning to clean the building and
prepare the food for the main meal of the day. When a
wrestler reaches the rank of juryo, placing him among the
top 66 sumo wrestlers in Japan, he no longer is required to
do chores for other rikishi. Those in the top 40 with ranks of
maegashira or better have their own servants.
4
An earlier version of this paper, Duggan and Levitt
(2001), derive a formal model of the incentives facing partic-
ipants. For wrestlers on the bubble, the incentive to rig matches
increases monotonically over the co urse of a tournament.
5
Wrestlers ranked between fth and tenth earn an annual
income—including only of cial wages, bonuses, and prize
money—of roughly $250,000 per year. The fortieth -ranked
wrestler earns approximately $170,000. The seventieth-
ranked wrestler receives only about $15,000 per year (no
of cial salary, just a small stipend to cover tournament
expenses, some prize money, and room and board). All
information on annual salaries are based on the authors’
calculations and information provided in Mina Hall (1997).
Unof cial sources of income such as endorsements would
likely increase the disp arity between the top and bottom
wrestlers.
FIGURE 1. PAYOFF TO TOURNAMENT WINS
1595VOL. 92 NO. 5 DUGGAN AND LEVITT: CORRUPTION IN SUMO WRESTLING
far from conclusive proof of match rigging.
Those wrestlers who are on the margin for
achieving the eighth win may exert greater ef-
fort because their reward for winning is larger.
We offer a number o f pieces of evid ence a gainst
this alternative hypothesis. First, whereas th e
wrestler who is on the margin for an eighth win
is victorious with a surprisingly high frequency,
the next time that those same two wrestlers face
each other, it is the
opponent
who has an un-
usually high win percentage.
6
This result sug-
gests that at least part of the currency used in
match rigging is promises of throwing future
matches in return for taking a fall today. Sec-
ond, win rates for wrestlers on the bubble vary
in accordance with factors predicted by theory
to support implicit collusion. For example, suc-
cess rates for wrestlers on the bubble rise
throughout the career (consistent with the de-
velopment of repu tation), but fall in the last year
of a wrestler’s career. T hird, match rigging dis-
appears during times of increased media scru-
tiny. Fourth, some wrestling stables (known as
heya
) appear to have worked out rec iprocity
agreements with other st ables such that wres-
tlers from either stable do exceptionally well on
the bubble against one another.
7
Finally, wres-
tlers identi ed as “not corrupt” by two former
sumo wrestlers who have alleged match rigging
do no better in matches on the bubble than in
typical matches, whereas those accused of being
corrupt are extremely successful o n the bubble.
It is dif cult to reconcile any of these ndings
with effort as the primary explanation.
The remainder of this paper is o rganized as
follows. Section I introduces the data used in
the analysis and presents the empirical evidence
documenting the strong performance of wres-
tlers on the bubble. Section II attempts to dis-
tinguish between increased effort and match
rigging as an explanation for the observed pat-
terns in the data and also considers the way in
which the market for rigged matches operates,
e.g., how contracts are enforced, the use of cash
payments versus promises of future thrown
matches, and individuals versus stables as the
level at which deals are brokered. Section III
concludes with a discussion of the broader eco-
nomic implications of our analysis.
I. Evidence of Strong Perfo rmanc e
on the Bubble
Our data set consists of almost every of cial
sumo match that took place in the top rank
(
Sekitori
) of Japanese sumo wrestling between
January 1989 and January 2000. Six tourna-
ments are held a year, with nearly 70 wrestlers
per tournament, and 15 bouts per wrestler.
Thus, our initial data set consists of over 64,000
wrestler-matches representing over 32,000 total
bouts (since there a re two wrestlers per bout). A
small number of observations (less than 5 per-
cent of the total data set) are discarded due to
missing data, c oding errors, or early withdrawal
from the tournament due to injury. A total of
281 wrestlers appear in our data, with th e aver-
age number of observations per wrest ler in a
randomly selected match equal to 554, and a
maximum of 990. The average number of total
matches betwee n the same two wrest lers com-
peting in a randomly selected match is 10; thus
we often have many observations involving the
same two wrestlers at different points in time.
For each observation, we know the identity of
the two competitors, who wins, the month and
year o f the tournament, and the day of the match
(tournaments last 15 days with one match per
wrestler per day). For roughly 98 percent of the
sample, we also know what wrestling stable the
wrestlers belong to; information is missing for
some wrestlers i n the early part of our sample
who had only a short stint in the top ranks.
We begin by looking at the distribution of
wins across wrestlers at the end of tournaments.
We expect that a disproportionate number of
wrestlers should nish wit h eight wins because
of the high payoff associated with the eighth
win (see Figure 1). To the extent that wrestlers
are rigging matches not only on t he nal day,
but also in the days immediately preceding the
end of the tournament, extra we ight should also
be observed on nine wins, as wrestlers who are
close to the margin on days 13 or 14 may buy
wins that ultimately were not needed to reach
eight wins due to subsequent victories. Figure
2 presents a histogram of nal wins for the
60,000 wres tler-tournament observations in
which a wrestler completes exactly 15 matches.
For purposes of comparison, we also present the
6
By the second subsequent meeting, the winning per-
centages revert back to the exp ected levels, sug gesting that
deals between individual wrestlers span only two matches.
7
Wrestlers in the same stable do not wrestle each other.
1596 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2002
expected pattern of results assuming that all
wrestlers are identical and that match outcomes
are independently di stributed.
Figure 2 provides clear visual evidence in
support o f the models prediction. Approxi-
mately 26.0 percent of all wrestlers nish with
exactly eight wins, compared to only 12.2 per-
cent with seven wins. The binomial distribution
predicts that these two outcomes should occur
with an equal frequency of 19.6 percent. The
null hypothesis that the probability of seven and
eight wins is equ al can be rejected at resounding
levels of statistical signi cance. Nine victories
also appears more often than would be ex-
pected. Although this d istortion is far less pro-
nounced visually, nine v ictories is signi cantly
more likely than six (16.2 percent versus 13.9
percent).
Further evidence that wrestlers on the bubble
win far more often than would be expected
comes fro m estimating regressions of the gen-
eral form
(1)
Win
ij t d
5
bBubble
ij td
1
g
Rankdiff
ijt
1
l
ij
1
d
it
1
e
ijtd
where
i
and
j
represent the two wrestlers,
t
corresponds to a particular tournament, and
d
is
the day of the tournament. The unit of observa-
tion is a wrestler-match. Bubble is a vector of
indicator variables capturing whether wrestler
i
or
j
is on the margin for reaching eight wins in
the bout in question. The Bubble variables are
coded 1 if only the wrestler is on the margin,
2
1 if only the opponent is on the margin, and 0
if neither or both of the combatants are on the
margin in the match.
Rankdiff
is the gap be-
tween the of cial ranking of wrestlers
i
and
j
entering tournament
t
. In some regressions, we
include xed effects for each wrestler a nd each
opponent; in other speci cations we include
wrestler-opponent interactions. In all cases, we
estimate linear probability models, with stan-
dard erro rs co rrected to take in to account the
fact that a match is included in the data set
twice—once for wrestler
i
and once for wrestler
j
.
Table 1 reports the excess win percentages
for wrestlers on the margin, by day, for the last
ve days of the tournament. On day 15, only
wrestlers with exactly s even wins are o n the
margin; on day 14, wrestlers with either six or
seven wins are on the margin, etc. The six
columns correspond to different regression
speci cations. The even columns include the
differences in ranks for the two wrestlers enter-
ing this tournament. The rst two columns have
no wrestler xed effects; columns (3) an d (4)
include both wrestler and opponent xed effects.
The nal two columns add wrestler-opponent
interactions so that th e identi cation comes
only from deviations in this match relative to
other matches involving the same two wrestlers.
The results in Table 1 are q uite similar across
speci cations.
8
Wrestlers on the bubble on day
15 are victorious roughly 25 percent more often
than would be expected. Win percentages are
elevated about 15 percent on day 14, 11 percent
on day 13, and 5 percent on day 12 for wrestlers
on the margin. There is no statistically signi -
cant evidence of elevated win rates for wrestlers
on the bubble on day 11. The pattern of coef -
cients is consistent with the hypothesis that th e
frequency of match rigging will rise as the tour-
nament comes to a close. If all of the excess
wins are due to rigging, then the results imply
that on day 15 half of the bubble matches are
crooked. For days 14, 1 3, and 12 respectively,
the estimated percentage of rigged matches is
roughly 28, 22, and 10 percent respectively.
8
Adding the difference in current rank between wres-
tlers has little impact on the other coef cients in the regres-
sion. The difference in ranks is an important predictor of
match outcomes when wrestler xed effects are excluded
from the model. The top-ranked wrestler facing an average
wrestler would be expected to win about 70 percent of the
time. Once we control for wrestler xed effects, however,
the explanatory power of the difference in ranks disappears.
FIGURE 2. WINS IN A SUMO TOURNAMENT
(ACTUAL VS. BINOMIAL)
1597VOL. 92 NO. 5 DUGGAN AND LEVITT: CORRUPTION IN SUMO WRESTLING
II. Distinguishing Between Match Rigging
and Effort
The empirical results presented thus far are
consistent with a model in which opponents
throw matches to allow wrestlers on t he margin
to achieve an eighth victory. The results, how-
ever, are also consistent with a scenario in
which effort is an important de terminant of the
match outcome, and wrestlers on the bubble,
having more to gain from a win, exert greater
effort.
9
In this section, we present a wide variety
of analyses that appear to con rm the corruption
story and rule out effort as the explanation.
A.
What Characteristics In uence the
Likelihood of Winning When on the Bubble?
We begin by analyzing the personal and sit-
uational characteristics that in uence the suc-
cess rate of the wrestler on th e bubble. One
potentially important determinant of the fre-
quency of match rigging is the p robability that
the collusive behavior will be detected. During
our sample, there have been two periods in
9
The results are also consistent with a model in which
wrestlers show altruism for one another, sacri cing their
own outcomes to help an opponent who has more to gain .
Given the nature of athletics and the nontrivial cost to the
wrestler of losing the match (roughly $10,000), the altruism
story strikes us as an unlikely explanation.
TABLE 1—EXCESS WIN PERCENTAGES FOR WRESTLERS ON THE MARGIN FOR ACHIEVING AN EIGHTH WIN,
BY DAY OF THE MATCH
On the Margin on: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Day 15 0.244 0.249 0.249 0.255 0.260 0.264
(0.019) (0.019) (0.018) (0.019) (0.022) (0.022)
Day 14 0.150 0.155 0.152 0.157 0.168 0.171
(0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.019) (0.019)
Day 13 0.096 0.107 0.110 0.118 0.116 0.125
(0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.019) (0.019)
Day 12 0.038 0.061 0.064 0.082 0.073 0.076
(0.017) (0.018) (0.017) (0.018) (0.020) (0.021)
Day 11 0.000 0.018 0.015 0.025 0.010 0.012
(0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.021) (0.021)
Rank difference 0.0053 0.0020 20.0020
(0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0004)
Constant 0.500 0.500
(0.000) (0.000)
R
2
0.008 0.018 0.030 0.031 0.0634 0.0653
Number of observations 64,272 62,708 64,272 62,708 64,272 62,708
Wrestler and opponent xed effects No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Wrestler-opponent interactions No No No No Yes Yes
Notes: The dependent variable in all regressions is an indicator variable corresponding to whether or not a wrestler wi ns the
match. The unit of observation is a wrestler-match. Values reported in the table are coef cients associated with an indicator
variable taking the value 1 if only the wrestler is on the margin for achieving eight wins, 21 if o nly the opponent is on the
margin for achieving eight wins, and 0 otherwise. On day 15, onl y wrestlers with seven wins are on the margin. On day 14,
wrestlers with six or seven wins are on the margin. On day 13, wrestlers with ve, six, or seven wins are on the margin, and
so on. The omitted category in all regressions is all wrestlers who are not on the margin for achieving eight wins, as well as
wrestlers in matches in which both participants are on the margin for eight wins. When a full set of wrestler and opponent
xed effects are included, the constant is omitted. In all cases, standard errors are corrected to account for the fact that there
are two observations per bout (one for each wrestler). The differences in the wrestler rank variable is the numerical rank order
of the wrestler minus that of his oppon ent, based on of cial rankings published prior to each tournament. This variable is
missing for part of our sample.
1598 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2002
which media attention has focused on match
rigging. The rst of these was in April and May
of 1996. A former sumo wrestler who had be-
come a stable-master came forward with alle-
gations of match ri gging. At the same time,
another former wrestler also came forward to
decry rigged matches. Ironically, both of these
men died a few weeks later, just hours apart, in
the same hospital. T his fueled speculation
among the media of foul play, although a sub-
sequent police investigation revealed no evi-
dence for th is. The second period of media
scrutiny took place in late 1999 early 2000. A
former sumo wrestler named Itai rai sed allega-
tions of match rigging that were wid ely covered
by the media, even in the United States. The
three tournaments in our sample that are most
likely to be affected by the media attention are
those held in May 1996, November 1999, and
January 2000.
The literature on repeated-play games (e.g.,
Drew Fudenberg and Jean Tirole, 1991) sug-
gests that the ability to sustain collusion should
be positively related to the frequency with
which two wrestlers e xpect to meet in the future
since more future meetings imply the availabil-
ity of more severe punishments for wrestlers
who d o not cooperate. Empirically, we p roxy
the expected frequency of future m atches using
two variables: (1) the number of meetings be-
tween the two wrestlers that took place in the
preceding year, and (2) whether the wrestler is
in the last year of his career. Although the
precise ending of a wrestler’s career is not
known in advance to the participants, it is likely
that signals of retirement are available (e.g.,
declining performance, injuries, etc.).
10
If it
takes time t o establish a reputation as a wrestler
who is willing to collude and who can be
trusted, then one might predict that the longer a
wrestler has been active in the top ranks of
sumo, the better he will do when he is on the
bubble, and also, the worse he will perform
when the opponent is on t he bubble.
Because there are a series of monetary prizes
given to wrestlers who have good records in a
given tournament, wrestlers in the running for
such prizes are unlikely to be willing to throw
matches.
11
The overall tournament champion
wins $100,000; the
juryo
champion wins
$20,000. In addition, $20,000 awards for “ ght-
ing spirit and “outstanding technique.” In order
to win those prizes, wrestlers must compile very
strong records. The potential value of a victory
for a wrestler in the running for such prizes is
likely to be at least as great as the value to a
wrestler on the margin for an eighth win.
A n al determinant of match rigging that we
consider is the possibility of coordinated match
rigging among stables of wrestlers. The lives of
sumo wrestlers center around the stable with
which they are associated. Stable-masters exert
a tremendous in uence over both the wrestling
career of wrestlers and their lives more gener-
ally.
12
Given the important role of the stable,
and the fact that stable-masters bene t from
having highly ranked wrestlers, it would not be
surprising if corruption were coordinated at the
stable level. For example, stables might have
collective reputations, with stable-masters en-
forcing punishments on wrestlers who pursue
their individual best interests at the expense of
the stable. Some stable-masters, on the other
hand, may not co ndone match rigging because
of ethical concerns o r risk aversion.
We empirically examine one particular form
of stable-level collusion: the presence of reci-
procity agreements across stables. If such deals
existed, one would expect both that wrestlers
from stable
A
will have very high win rates
when on the bubble facing wrestlers from stable
B
, and v ice versa.
13
It is dif cult to tell an
alternative story that would account for such a
pattern in t he data. For instance, if effort is the
10
In order to minimize endogeneity, we exclude the very
last tournament of a wrestler’s career. It is possible that a
loss on the bubble may drop the wrestler out of the top level
of wrestlers, inducing retirement. Including the last tourna-
ment of a wrestler’s career slightly increased the magnitude
and statistical signi cance of the coef cient.
11
Although we do not directly observe which wrestlers
might be under consideration for these prizes, having one of
the ve best records (plus ties) up until that point in the
tournament is an excellent predictor. Wrestlers with one of
the ve best records in the tournament entering days 13, 14,
or 15 win a prize 50 percent of the time. Less than ve
percent of wrestlers with reco rds outside the top ve on
days 1315 eventually win a prize.
12
For instance, it is expected that the foremost sumo wres-
tler in a stable will marry the daughter of the stable-master.
13
The variable we use to test this empirically is the
overall win rate for wrestlers on t he bubble in matches
involving both a wrestler from stable A and a wrestler from
stable B (excluding the current match). This variable re ects
both stable As success on the bubble against stable B and
stable B’s success against stable A.
1599VOL. 92 NO. 5 DUGGAN AND LEVITT: CORRUPTION IN SUMO WRESTLING
story, then stables with wrestlers capable of
exerting particularly high effort when they need
a win might also be expected to have wrestlers
who rise to the occasion when faced with the
opportunity to beat a very motivated opponent,
leading to a zero or negative correlation. Simi-
larly, if one stable has developed speci c tech-
niques that provide it with an a dvantage over a
particular stable, success rates on the bubble
will again be negatively related.
These various hypotheses are tested in Table 2.
Because our interest is in how these factors
in uence success on the bubble, the table re-
ports only the coef cients on the
interactions
between these various factors and the outcome
of bubble matches, i.e., any incremental impact
that the se factors have on bubble matches above
and beyond their impact in nonbubble matches.
Also included in the speci cations, but not
shown in the table, are t he main effects. Column
(1) is the baseline speci cation. Column (2)
adds both wrestler and opponent xed effects.
Column (3) also includes wrestler-opponent in-
teractions. The results are generally quite simi-
lar across the three columns of the table.
The top row of the table is the main e ffect of
a wrestler being on the bubble, which leads to
an excess win likelihood of roughly 12–16 per-
centage points. In those tournaments with a high
level of media scrutiny, however, these excess
wins completely disappear.
14
In two of the three
speci cations, th e performance of wrestlers on
the bubble in high and low media scrutiny tour-
naments is statistically signi cant at the 0.05
level. In none of the three columns can one
reject the null h ypothesis that wrestlers on the
bubble in high-scrutiny tournaments do any bet-
ter than chance. In the words of Supreme Court
Justice Louis D. Brandeis, “Sunlight is said to
be th e best disinfectant.”
15
When the opponent is in the running for
winning one of the special prizes awarded, any
bene t of being on the bubble also disappears.
This result is consistent with opponents in the
running for prizes being unwilling to throw a
match.
The variables designed to capture factors in-
14
To calculate the overall excess win percent for a
wrestler on th e bubble in a p eriod of high media scr utiny,
the coef cients in rows 1 and 2 are added together.
15
We thank an anonymous referee for bringing this very
appropriate quote to our attention.
TABLE 2—DETERMINANTS OF EXCESS WIN L IKELIHOODS
FOR WRESTLERS ON THE BUBBLE
Variable (1) (2) (3)
Wrestler on bubble 0.126 0.117 0.155
(0.026) (0.026) (0.029)
Wrestler on bubble
interacted with:
High media 20.188 20.177 20.146
scrutiny (0.071) (0.071) (0.080)
Opponent in 20.149 20.129 20.156
running for a
prize this
tournament
(0.047) (0.046) (0.052)
Number of 20.0048 20.0031 20.0024
meetings
between two
opponents in
the last year
(0.0082) (0.0081) (0.0096)
Wrestler on
bubble
20.0361 20.0195 20.0346
in his last year
of competing
(0.0398) (0.0395) (0.0493)
Years in sumo for 0.0077 0.0077 0.0091
wrestler on
bubble
(0.0036) (0.0036) (0.0043)
Winning 0.272 0.293
percentage in
other bubble
matches
between these
two stables
(0.059) (0.058)
R
2
0.016 0.074 0.246
Wrestler and
opponent xed
effects?
No Yes Yes
Wrestler-opponent
interactions?
No No Yes
Notes: The dependent variable in all three regressions is an
indicator variable corresponding to whether or not a wres-
tler wins the match. In addition to the listed interaction
terms, all main effects are also included in the speci ca-
tions. Wrestler on bubble is an indicator variable that equals
1 (21) if the wrestler (opponent) is on the bubble on days
13, 14, or 15 (record of 7-7, 7-6, 6-7, 7-5, 6-6, or 5-7) but
the opponent (wrestler) is not, and 0 otherwise. Matches
from 1989, the rst year of our sample, are excluded be-
cause the variable for the number of matches between the
two wrestlers in the previous year cannot be computed .
Observations where stables are unknown or no two wres-
tlers from the stables ever meet on the bubble in our data set
are also excluded from the sample. The number of obser-
vations is consequently 42,788. Standard errors are cor-
rected to account for the fact that there are two observations
per bout (one for each wrestler).
1600 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2002
uencing implicit collusion achieve mixed re-
sults. The number of matches between two
wrestlers in the preceding year has an unex-
pected negative impact on a wrestler’s likeli-
hood of winning a match on the bubble,
although the coef cient is substantively small
and carries a
t
-statistic of far less than 1 in all of
the speci cations. W restlers in the last year of
their career do slightly worse than e xpected on
the bubble, although again the result is not
statistically signi cant. With the exception of
the last year, ho wever, success on the bubble
increases over the career. A ve-year veteran is
about 4 percentage points (off a baseline of 13
percentage points) more likely to win on the
bubble than a rookie. This last result is consis-
tent with the importance of developing a
reputation.
Finally, the bottom row of coef cients in
Table 2 measures the extent to which a wres-
tler’s success on the bubble today is in uenced
by overall success rates (excluding this match)
when wrestlers from that stable meet wrestlers
from the opponent’s stable and one of the wres-
tlers is on the bubble.
16
The coef cient is
strongly positive and statistically signi cant. As
noted above, that result that is dif cult t o rec-
oncile with any hypothesis other than stable-
coordinated collusion. Moreover, the size of the
coef cient is large: for each 10-percentage-
point increase in success in other bubble
matches between these two stables, the wrestler
on the bu bble is 3 percentage p oints more likely
to win today, controlling for other factors.
B.
What Happens When Wrestlers M eet
Again in the Future?
If collusion is the reason that wrestlers on the
bubble p erform well, then the opponent must be
compensated in some way for losing the match.
It is possible that such payments are made in
cash, or in promises to return the favor in the
future. The likelihood that two wrestlers will
meet again soon is high: in our data 74 percent
of the wrestlers who meet when one is on the
margin for eight wins will face one another
again within a year.
Table 3 explores the pattern of match out-
comes ov er time for wrestlers who meet when
one is on the margin. The even columns include
wrestler-opponent interactions so identi cation
of the parameters comes only from variation in
outcomes involving the same two opponents;
the odd columns do not. The regression speci-
cations include in dicator variables categoriz-
ing the timing of the meetings between two
wrestlers relative to the match where one wres-
tler is on the bubble. The omitted category is
matches preceding a bubble meeting by at least
three matches.
17
Focusing rst on columns (1) and (2), which
correspond to all meetings on the bubble, there
are no systematic differences in outcomes in the
two matches preceding the match on the bubble,
as re ected in the statistically insigni cant c o-
ef cients in the top row. When the wrestler is
on the bubble (second row), he is much more
likely to win, consistent with the earlier tables.
The p arameter of greatest interest is the nega-
tive co ef cient for the rst meeting between the
two wrestlers after the match in which the wres-
tler is on the bubble. The wrestler who was on
the margin in the last meeting is approximately
seven percent
less
likely to win than would
otherwise be predicted. This nding is consis-
tent with part of the compensation for throwing
a match being t he promise of the opponent
returning the favor in the next meeting. There is
no evidence that any return of favors extends
beyond the next match, as two and three
matches out the winning percentages return to
normal.
The nal four columns of Table 3 replicate
the rst two columns, except that the sample is
divided into cases where the wrestler wins when
on the margin versus instances when the wres-
tler loses when on the margin.
18
One would not
expect a wrestler to intentionally lose in future
meetings to an opponentwho does not throw the
match on the margin. Thus, breaking down the
16
Because wrestlers do not change stables over the
course of their careers, there is no usable variation in this
variable when wrestler-opponent interactions are included
in column (3).
17
We have experimented with other groupings of
matches, f or instance allowing a different coef cient for
matches preceding/following the bubble match by mo re
than t hree meetings. The parameters of interest are not
sensitive to alternative speci cations.
18
In columns (3)–(6), the actual matches taking place on
the bubble are excluded from the regression si nce there is no
variation. In columns (3) and (4), all bubble matches are
won by the wrestler on the bubble; in columns (5) and (6),
no matches are won by the wrestler on the bubble.
1601VOL. 92 NO. 5 DUGGAN AND LEVITT: CORRUPTION IN SUMO WRESTLING
data in this way provides a natural test of the
hypothesis that the poo r performance in the next
match is due to a deferred payoff to an opponent
who threw a match. The data provide clear
support for the collusion hypothesis. Wrestlers
who win on the bubble tend to do slightly better
than expected leading up to the bubble match,
then do much worse in the next meeting with
the same opponent. Relative to the surrounding
matches, the rst post-bubble match sees the
wrestler losing approximately 10 percentage
points more frequently than would be expected
(i.e., row 3 minus row 1).
The pattern for wrestlers who lose to the oppo-
nent when on the margin for achieving eight wins
is very different. In the matches just prior to the
bubble match, the wrestler is slightly underper-
forming. This continues unaffected through the
post-bubble matches as well. Unlike columns (1)–
(4), there is no downward spike in wins following
the bubble match. The nding that winners on the
bubble fare badly the next time they face the same
opponent, but losers do not, is consistent with the
match-rigging hypothesis, but not with an effort
story. If increased effort is responsible for strong
performances in matches on the margin, there is
no reason to expect systematic underperformance
the next time the two wrestlers meet, and certainly
19
When two wrestlers meet and both are on the bubble,
there is similarly no evidence that the wrestler who wins
fares more poorly the next time the two wrestlers meet. Thi s
is consistent with no match rig ging occurring when both
wrestlers are on the bubble, as predicted by the model.
More generally, there is no evidence of negative serial
correlation in match outcomes. When multiple lags of past
match outcomes between the two wrestlers are added to the
speci cations, the coef cients are positive.
TABLE 3—WIN PERCENTAGES IN PRECEDING AND SUBSEQUENT MATCHES
(For Two Wrestlers Who Meet When One is on the Margin in the Final Three Days of a Tournament)
Variable
All Matches on the
Margin
Only Matches in
Which the Wrestler on
the Margin Wins
Only Matches in
Which the Wrestler on
the Margin Loses
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
One or two matches prior to the 20.002 0.005 0.0 20 0.0 19 20.041 20.035
bubble match (0.009) (0.012) (0.011) (0.017) (0.016) (0.022)
Bubble match 0.151 0.164
(0.010) (0.014)
First meeting after bubble match 20.073 20.062 20.082 20.079 20.056 20.040
(0.011) (0.015) (0.015) (0.020) (0.0 20) (0.0 27)
Second meeting after bubble match 20.002 0.005 0.031 0.028 20.061 20.039
(0.013) (0.016) (0.017) (0.022) (0.0 23) (0.0 30)
Three or more meetings after 20.010 0.012 0.013 0.022 20.045 20.013
bubble match (0.006) (0.011) (0.007) (0.014) (0.0 08) (0.0 17)
Constant 0.500 0.50 0 0 .500
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Wrestler-opponent interactions? No Yes No Yes No Yes
R
2
0.008 0.271 0.002 0.279 0.002 0.279
Notes: Entries in the table are regression estimates of the outcomes of matches between, after, and co ntemporaneous with
these two wrestlers meeting when one wrestler is on the margin for achieving eight wins on the last three days of the
tournament. T he dependent variable in all regressions is an indicator variable for whether the wrestler wins a match. The unit
of observation is a wrestler match. The rst two columns correspond to all wrestlers who meet when one is on the margin.
In columns (3) and (4), the coef cients reported corr espond only to those cases where the wrestler on the bubble wins the
match. Columns (5) and (6) report coef cients only for those wrestlers on the bubble who lose the match. Columns (3) and
(5) are estimated jointly, as are columns (4) and (6). Except for columns (1) and (2 ), bubble matches are excluded from the
regressions. The excluded category in all regressions are matches occurring more than two matches prior to a bubble match
and not falling into any of the other categories named. When a full set of wrestler and opponent xed effects are included,
the constant is omitted. In all cases, standard errors ar e corrected to account for the fact that th ere are two observations per
bout (one for each wrestler). Number of observations is equal to 64,273.
1602 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2002
not exclusively among those who won on the
bubble.
19
The payment-in-kind story suggested by the
results above is unlikely to be the only form of
compensation for wrestlers who throw matches.
Based on Table 3, roughly two-thirds of the
excess wins garnered on the b ubble are returned
the next ti me the two wrestlers meet. This
price—t wo-thirds of a match down the road in
return for throwing a match today—is too low
to represent the only form of payment. When
rumors circulate about match rigging in sumo,
they often suggest the presence of cash trans-
fers, although we are able to provide no evi-
dence about this channel.
C.
Do the Data Con rm Public Allegations of
Cheating by Sumo Insiders?
Two former sumo wrestlers have made pub-
lic the names of 29 wrestlers who they allege to
be corrupt and 14 wrestlers who they claim
refuse to rig matches (Keisuke Itai, 2000; Ona-
ruto, 2000;
Shukan Post
, 2000).
20
In this sec-
tion, we investigate whether the performance on
the bubble of these two groups of wrestlers
systematically di ffers. If strong performance on
the bubble is due to match rigging and t he
allegations are true, then one would expect the
corrupt wrestlers to do extremely well on the
bubble, whereas the honest wrestlers would do
no better in bubble matches than on any other
match.
To test this hypothesis, we estimate a re-
gression identical to equation (1), but includ-
ing a full set of interactions between whether
a match is on the bubble and the classi cation
of each wrestler and his opponent as either
corrupt, clean,” or status unknown.” Only
43 of the 281 wrestlers (15 percent) in our
sample are speci cally identi ed as either
corrupt or clean. The remainder are classi ed
as status unknown. The whistle-blowers were
more likely to identify prominent wrestlers
with l ong c areers, however, so over 60 per-
cent of the matches in our sample involve at
least one wrestler identi ed by name as either
clean or corrupt.
Table 4 reports the results of the estimation.
All of the coef cients in the table come from a
single regression. The values in the table repre-
sent excess win percentages on the bubble, i.e.,
how much better a wrestler does when on the
bubble relative to matches in which neither
wrestler is on the b ubble. The columns of the
table identify the status of the wrestler on the
bubble—the wrestler who wants to buy a vic-
tory. The rows correspond to the status of the
opponent of the wrestler on the bubble—the
wrestler who might want to sell a win. Wh en
two wrestlers identi ed as corru pt me et on the
bubble, the one who needs the victory is 2 6
percentage points more likely to win the ma tch
than if those two wrestlers met with neither on
the bubble. This excess win percentage is highly
statistically signi cant. When a corrupt wrestler
meets a wrestler classi ed as “status unknown,”
the results are very similar. Win percentages for
the wrestler needing the victory when both
wrestlers are classi ed a s “status unknown” are
also highly elevated (18.1 percentage points
higher), but not quite as extreme. In stark con-
trast, none of the ve coef cients involving
wrestlers identi ed as clean are statistically sig-
ni cant from zero. This implies t hat the out-
comes o f bubble matches involving a clean
wrestler are no different than the results when
the same two wrestlers meet, but neither is on
the bubble. This result holds true regardless of
whether the cl ean wrestler is himself on the
bubble or facing a wrestler who is on the bub-
ble. Thus, Table 4 provides strong con rmation
not only of the claim that elevated win percent-
ages on the bubble are due to m atch rigging, but
also that the allegations made by the two sumo
insiders appear to be truthful. Moreover, it ap-
pears that most of th e wrestlers not sp eci cally
named by the whistle-blowers are corrupt, since
their outcomes differ only slightly from those
wrestlers named as corrupt.
III. Conclus ion
This paper provides strong statistical analysis
documenting match rigging in sumo wrestling.
The incentive structure of promotion leads to
gains from trade between wrestlers on the mar-
gin for achieving a winning record and their
opponents. We show that wrestlers win a dis-
proportionate share of the matches when they
are on the margin. Increased effort cannot
20
The books that we cite are published only in Japanese.
We thank Serguey Braguinsky both for bringing the exis-
tence of this information to our attention and for translating
the relevant material for us.
1603VOL. 92 NO. 5 DUGGAN AND LEVITT: CORRUPTION IN SUMO WRESTLING
explain the ndings. Match rigging disappears
in times of increased media scrutiny. Wrestlers
who are victorious when on the bubble lose more
frequently than would be expected the next time
they meet that opponent, suggesting that part of
the payment for throwing a match is future pay-
ment in-kind. Reciprocity agreements between
stables of wrestlers appear to exist, suggesting that
collusive behavior is not carried out solely by
individualactors. Allegationsby sumo insiders are
demonstrated to be veri ed in our data.
While sumo wrestling per se is not of direct
interest to economists, the case st udy that it
provides is po tentially of usefulness to the eco-
nomic analysis of corruption. Anecdotal allega-
tions of corrupt practices among sumo wrestlers
have occasionally surfaced, but have been dis-
missed as impossible to substantiate. In this
paper, we d emonstrate that the combination of a
clear understanding of the incentives facing par-
ticipants combined with creative uses of d ata
can reveal overwhelming statistical evidence of
corruption. Details of the corrupt practices, the
data sources, and the telltale patterns in the data
will all vary from one application to the next.
Nonetheless, the success of our study in docu-
menting the predicted patterns of corruption in
one context raises the hope that parallel studies
with more substantive economic focus may
yield similar results.
Moreover, our analysis provides insight into
how to combat corruption. First, the match rig-
ging we identify can be directly linked to the
arti cially imposed n onlinearity in incentives
for wrestlers wh o achieve a winning record.
21
Removing this distortion to incentives would
eliminate the bene ts of corruption. Second,
match rigging appears to be sensitive to th e
costs of detection. Increased media scrutiny
alone is suf cient to eliminate the collusive
behavior. Presumably, other approaches to rais-
ing the expected punishment would likewise be
effective. Third, at least in the sumo context,
insiders appear to have good information about
who is corrupt. Providing strong incentives for
whistle-blowers, particularly when suc h accusa-
tions ca n be corroborated by objective data
analysis, may prove effective in restraining cor-
rupt behavior.
While perhaps beyond the scope of this pa-
per, a question of interest is why those in charge
of the sumo wrestling have not attempted to
eliminate corruption, either by eliminating the
nonlinearity or by increasing expected punish-
ments. A partial answer is that there are barriers
to entry for a second sumo league, so the com-
petitive pressure exerted on th e current sumo
association is limited.
22
A second possibility is
21
Nonlinearities of this sort have been shown to distort
behavior in many other contexts as well, including Robert
Topel (1983) and Judith Chevalier and Glenn Ellison
(1997).
22
It is worth noting that the popularity of sumo wrestling
has declined substantially over the last two decades, sug-
gesting that other forms of recreation are substitutes.
TABLE 4—EXCESS WIN PERCENTAGES ON THE BUBBLE FOR WRESTLERS LABELED BY SUMO
INSIDERS AS “CORRUPT OR “CLEAN
Wrestler on the Bubble Is Identi ed as:
Corrupt Status Unknown Clean
Opponent of
wrestler on the
bubble is
identi ed as:
Corrupt 0.260 0.270 20.010
(0.037) (0.021) (0.038)
Status 0.271 0.181 0.041
unknown (0.021) (0.019) (0.031)
Clean 0.036 20.033 0.022
(0.027) (0.035) (0.074)
Notes: Entries in the table are coef cien ts from a regression with full set of interactions
between whether a match is on the bubble and the classi cation of a wrestler and his opponent
as clean, corrupt, or status unknown by two sumo insiders (Itai, 2000; Onaruto, 2000; Shukan
Post, 2000). The regression is identical to equation (1) in the text, except for the inclusion of
the aforementioned interactions. Twenty-nine wrestlers are categorized as corrupt, 14 are
classi ed as clean. Th e remainder of wrestlers are not speci cally named and are categorized
as status unknown. Stan dard errors are corrected to take into accou nt that there are two
observations per bout (one for each wrestler). Number of observations is equal to 64,273.
1604 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2002
that the nonlinear payoff structure generates
interest in otherwise unimportant matches on the
nal days of the tournament. For the same rea-
son that wrestlers want to rig the matches on the
bubble, the fans are interested in the outcome.
REFERENCES
Becker, Gary S. and Stigler, George J. “Law En-
forcement, Malfeasance, and the Compensa-
tion of Enforcers.
Journal of Legal Studies
,
January 1974,
3
(1), pp. 119.
Chevalier , Judith and Ellison, Glenn. “Risk-
Taking by Mutual Funds as a Response to
Incentives.”
Journal of Political Economy
,
December 1997,
105
(6), pp. 1167–200.
DiTella, Rafael and Schargrodsky, Ernesto. “The
Role of Wages and Auditing during a C rack-
down on Corruption in the City of Buenos
Aires. Mimeo, Harvard Business School,
2000.
Duggan, Mark and Levitt, Steven. Winning Isn’t
Everything: Corruption in Sumo Wrestling.”
National Bureau of Economic Research (Cam-
bridge, MA) Working Paper No. 7798, 2001.
Fisman, Ray. “Estimating the Value of Political
Connections.”
American Economic Review
,
September 2001,
91
(4), pp. 1095–102.
Fudenberg, Drew and Tirole, Jean.
Game th eory
.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1991.
Hall, Mina.
The big book of sumo.
Berkeley,
CA: Stonebridge Press, 1997.
Itai, Keisuke.
Nakabon
. Tokyo: Shogakkan
Press, 2000.
Leff, Nathaniel. “Economic Development through
Bureaucratic Corruption.”
American Behav-
ioral S cientist
, November 1964,
8
(3), pp.
8 –14.
Mauro, Paulo. Corruption and Growth.”
Quar-
terly Journal of Economics
, August 1995,
110
(2), pp. 681–711.
McAfee, R. Preston. “Bidding Rings.”
American
Economic Review
, June 1992,
82
(3), pp.
579–99.
Onaruto.
Yaocho
. Tokyo: Line Books, 2000.
Porter, Robert H. and Zona, J. Do ugla s. “De tec-
tion of Bid Rigging in Procurement Auc-
tions.
Journal of Political Economy
, June
1993,
101
(3), pp. 51838.
Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert W. “Corrup-
tion.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
, Au-
gust 1993,
108
(3), pp. 599 617.
Shukan Post.
Shukan Post-wa Yaocho-wo Ko
Hojite Ki ta
. Tokyo: Shogakkan Bunko, 2000.
Stigler, Stephen.
The history of statistics: The
measurement of uncertainty before 1900
.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
1986.
Topel, Robert. “On Layoffs and Unemployment
Insurance.”
American Economic Review
,
September 1983,
73
(4), pp. 54159 .
Transparenc y International. Corruption Per-
ceptions Index Press Release.” Berlin, Ger-
many, Se ptember 13, 2000.
West, Mark. “Legal Rules and Social Norms in
Japan’s Secret World of Sumo.
Journal of
Legal Studies
, January 1997,
26
(1), pp. 165–
201.
1605VOL. 92 NO. 5 DUGGAN AND LEVITT: CORRUPTION IN SUMO WRESTLING